Checkout
Cart: $0.00 - (0 items )

The Cantillon Effect Explained: Why Inflation Helps The State At Your Expense

Via SchiffGold.com,

The Cantillon Effect, named after 18th-century economist Richard Cantillon, describes the way newly created money flows through an economy, affecting different sectors and social classes unevenly. When a central bank like the Federal Reserve injects new money into the economy – often through measures like quantitative easing or low interest rates – this money doesn’t distribute itself evenly. Instead, it creates ripple effects that impact different people in distinct ways, often favoring the wealthy and disadvantaging lower-income individuals. The Austrian school of economics uses Cantillon’s observations as a lens to critique monetary policy, particularly in how it exacerbates inequality and distorts prices.

To understand Cantillon effects, consider the mechanics of monetary expansion.

When the central bank injects new money, it usually flows first to financial institutions, corporations, and government contractors, often through bond purchases or direct lending programs. These recipients gain early access to freshly created money, which gives them an advantage: they can spend or invest it before prices have risen to reflect the increased money supply. By the time this money trickles down to the broader economy, prices may have already increased, diminishing the purchasing power of wages and savings held by average consumers.

This phenomenon is directly tied to inflation. When new money is introduced, it often leads to a general rise in prices across the economy, though this effect is not immediate or uniform. For those at the top, the initial wave of new money creates lucrative opportunities: they can buy assets like stocks, real estate, or commodities before these prices are driven up by inflation. However, for the average worker or consumer, inflation manifests in a more damaging way. By the time new money circulates through the economy to the broader public, the prices of essential goods and services—like housing, food, and fuel—have already risen, eroding the purchasing power of wages and savings.

The Cantillon Effect, therefore, highlights a key criticism of inflationary monetary policy: it benefits those who have first access to new money at the expense of those who do not. Wealthier individuals, businesses, and financial entities are often the first recipients, allowing them to use this new money to their advantage by investing in assets that outpace inflation. Meanwhile, those lower on the economic ladder experience rising costs without a proportional increase in income, which erodes their purchasing power.

The Austrian school of economics views these distortions as symptomatic of a flawed monetary system. Austrian economists argue that when the money supply is manipulated, it sends false signals throughout the economy, creating what economist Ludwig von Mises called “malinvestment.” In a natural market, prices reflect genuine supply and demand, guiding resources to their most efficient uses. However, when the central bank expands the money supply, it artificially lowers interest rates, leading businesses to take on investments that may not be sustainable in the long run. For example, cheap credit may encourage excessive borrowing for real estate projects or speculative investments, inflating asset bubbles. When these bubbles inevitably burst, it’s typically lower-income workers who bear the brunt through job losses and economic contraction.

The Cantillon Effect is a critical aspect of how inflation disproportionately impacts the poor. Wealthy individuals and corporations, who have easier access to credit and investments, can protect themselves from inflation by diversifying into assets that appreciate in value. They may own real estate, stocks, or commodities—assets that tend to rise in price as the value of the dollar declines. In contrast, working-class consumers often hold their wealth primarily in cash or limited savings, which do not keep pace with inflation. They feel the direct impact of rising prices on essentials, while their wages stagnate or grow slower than inflation.

From an Austrian perspective, these effects reveal the inherent injustice of a fiat currency system. When the money supply can be expanded at will, the purchasing power of the currency continually erodes, hurting those who depend on stable prices to make ends meet. Austrian economists argue for a return to sound money principles, such as a gold standard, which limit the ability of central banks to expand the money supply arbitrarily. Under a sound money system, prices would be more stable, preserving the value of wages and savings over time.

The Cantillon Effect thus serves as a powerful illustration of how inflationary monetary policy can lead to unintended, but deeply damaging, social consequences. It underscores the Austrian view that central bank policies, while often well-intentioned, tend to exacerbate inequality and create cycles of boom and bust. For the poor and working class, inflation means diminished purchasing power, greater economic vulnerability, and reduced social mobility. By allowing markets rather than central banks to set the supply of money, the Austrian school contends that economies could achieve more equitable and sustainable growth, free from the distortions and inequities inherent in inflationary policies.

Loading…

INVESTING BOOKS

Be the first to know when NEW books are released!

We don’t spam! Read our privacy policy for more info.

Write a Reply or Comment:

Back to top